Greek Finance Minister Yanis Varoufakis |
GREEK FINANCE MINISTER
EXPLAINS HIS WORLDVIEW:
In 2008, capitalism had its
second global spasm. The financial crisis set off a chain reaction that pushed Europe
into a downward spiral that continues to this day. Europe’s present situation
is not merely a threat for workers, for the dispossessed, for the bankers, for
social classes or, indeed, nations. No, Europe’s current posture poses a threat
to civilisation as we know it. If my prognosis is correct, and
we are not facing just another cyclical slump soon to be overcome, the question
that arises for radicals is this: should we welcome this crisis of European
capitalism as an opportunity to replace it with a better system? Or should we
be so worried about it as to embark upon a campaign for stabilising European
capitalism? To me, the answer is clear.
Europe’s crisis is far less likely to give birth to a better alternative to
capitalism than it is to unleash dangerously regressive forces that have the
capacity to cause a humanitarian bloodbath, while extinguishing the hope for
any progressive moves for generations to come.
For this view I have been
accused, by well-meaning radical voices, of being “defeatist” and of trying to
save an indefensible European socioeconomic system. This criticism, I confess,
hurts. And it hurts because it contains more than a kernel of truth. I share the view that this
European Union is typified by a large democratic deficit that, in combination
with the denial of the faulty architecture of its monetary union, has put
Europe’s peoples on a path to permanent recession. And I also bow to the
criticism that I have campaigned on an agenda founded on the assumption that
the left was, and remains, squarely defeated. I confess I would much rather be
promoting a radical agenda, the raison d’être of which is to replace European
capitalism with a different system. Yet my aim here is to offer a
window into my view of a repugnant European capitalism whose implosion, despite
its many ills, should be avoided at all costs. It is a confession intended to
convince radicals that we have a contradictory mission: to arrest the freefall
of European capitalism in order to buy the time we need to formulate its alternative.
Why a Marxist?
When I chose the subject of my
doctoral thesis, back in 1982, I deliberately focused on a highly mathematical
topic within which Marx’s thought was irrelevant. When, later on, I embarked on
an academic career, as a lecturer in mainstream economics departments, the
implicit contract between myself and the departments that offered me
lectureships was that I would be teaching the type of economic theory that left
no room for Marx. In the late 1980s, I was hired by the University of Sydney’s
school of economics in order to keep out a leftwing candidate (although I did
not know this at the time).
After I returned to Greece in
2000, I threw my lot in with the future prime minister George Papandreou,
hoping to help stem the return to power of a resurgent right wing that wanted
to push Greece towards xenophobia both domestically and in its foreign policy.
As the whole world now knows, Papandreou’s party not only failed to stem
xenophobia but, in the end, presided over the most virulent neoliberal
macroeconomic policies that spearheaded the eurozone’s so-called bailouts thus,
unwittingly, causing the return of Nazis to the streets of Athens. Even though
I resigned as Papandreou’s adviser early in 2006, and turned into his
government’s staunchest critic during his mishandling of the post-2009 Greek
implosion, my public interventions in the debate on Greece and Europe have
carried no whiff of Marxism.
Given all this, you may be
puzzled to hear me call myself a Marxist. But, in truth, Karl Marx was
responsible for framing my perspective of the world we live in, from my
childhood to this day. This is not something that I often volunteer to talk
about in “polite society” because the very mention of the M-word switches
audiences off. But I never deny it either. After a few years of addressing
audiences with whom I do not share an ideology, a need has crept up on me to
talk about Marx’s imprint on my thinking. To explain why, while an unapologetic
Marxist, I think it is important to resist him passionately in a variety of
ways. To be, in other words, erratic in one’s Marxism.
If my whole academic career
largely ignored Marx, and my current policy recommendations are impossible to
describe as Marxist, why bring up my Marxism now? The answer is simple: Even my
non-Marxist economics was guided by a mindset influenced by Marx.
A radical social theorist can
challenge the economic mainstream in two different ways, I always thought. One
way is by means of immanent criticism. To accept the mainstream’s axioms and
then expose its internal contradictions. To say: “I shall not contest your
assumptions but here is why your own conclusions do not logically flow on from
them.” This was, indeed, Marx’s method of undermining British political
economics. He accepted every axiom by Adam Smith and David Ricardo in order to
demonstrate that, in the context of their assumptions, capitalism was a
contradictory system. The second avenue that a radical theorist can pursue is,
of course, the construction of alternative theories to those of the
establishment, hoping that they will be taken seriously.
My view on this dilemma has
always been that the powers that be are never perturbed by theories that embark
from assumptions different to their own. The only thing that can destabilise
and genuinely challenge mainstream, neoclassical economists is the
demonstration of the internal inconsistency of their own models. It was for this
reason that, from the very beginning, I chose to delve into the guts of
neoclassical theory and to spend next to no energy trying to develop
alternative, Marxist models of capitalism. My reasons, I submit, were quite
Marxist.
When called upon to comment on
the world we live in, I had no alternative but to fall back on Marxist
tradition
When called upon to comment on
the world we live in, I had no alternative but to fall back on the Marxist
tradition which had shaped my thinking ever since my metallurgist father
impressed upon me, when I was still a child, the effect of technological
innovation on the historical process. How, for instance, the passage from the
bronze age to the iron age sped up history; how the discovery of steel greatly
accelerated historical time; and how silicon-based IT technologies are
fast-tracking socioeconomic and historical discontinuities.
My first encounter with Marx’s
writings came very early in life, as a result of the strange times I grew up
in, with Greece exiting the nightmare of the neofascist dictatorship of
1967-74. What caught my eye was Marx’s mesmerising gift for writing a dramatic
script for human history, indeed for human damnation, that was also laced with
the possibility of salvation and authentic spirituality.
Marx created a narrative
populated by workers, capitalists, officials and scientists who were history’s
dramatis personae. They struggled to harness reason and science in the context
of empowering humanity while, contrary to their intentions, unleashing demonic
forces that usurped and subverted their own freedom and humanity.
This dialectical perspective,
where everything is pregnant with its opposite, and the eager eye with which
Marx discerned the potential for change in what seemed to be the most
unchanging of social structures, helped me to grasp the great contradictions of
the capitalist era. It dissolved the paradox of an age that generated the most
remarkable wealth and, in the same breath, the most conspicuous poverty. Today,
turning to the European
crisis, the crisis in the United States and the long-term stagnation of
Japanese capitalism, most commentators fail to appreciate the dialectical
process under their nose. They recognise the mountain of debts and banking
losses but neglect the opposite side of the same coin: the mountain of idle
savings that are “frozen” by fear and thus fail to convert into productive
investments. A Marxist alertness to binary oppositions might have opened their
eyes.
A major reason why established
opinion fails to come to terms with contemporary reality is that it never
understood the dialectically tense “joint production” of debts and surpluses,
of growth and unemployment, of wealth and poverty, indeed of good and evil.
Marx’s script alerted us these binary oppositions as the sources of history’s
cunning.
From my first steps of thinking
like an economist, to this very day, it occurred to me that Marx had made a discovery
that must remain at the heart of any useful analysis of capitalism. It was the
discovery of another binary opposition deep within human labour. Between
labour’s two quite different natures: i) labour as a value-creating activity
that can never be quantified in advance (and is therefore impossible to
commodify), and ii) labour as a quantity (eg, numbers of hours worked) that is
for sale and comes at a price. That is what distinguishes labour from other
productive inputs such as electricity: its twin, contradictory, nature. A
differentiation-cum-contradiction that political economics neglected to make
before Marx came along and that mainstream economics is steadfastly refusing to
acknowledge today.
Both electricity and labour can
be thought of as commodities. Indeed, both employers and workers struggle to
commodify labour. Employers use all their ingenuity, and that of their HR
management minions, to quantify, measure and homogenise labour. Meanwhile,
prospective employees go through the wringer in an anxious attempt to commodify
their labour power, to write and rewrite their CVs in order to portray
themselves as purveyors of quantifiable labour units. And there’s the rub. If
workers and employers ever succeed in commodifying labour fully, capitalism will
perish. This is an insight without which capitalism’s tendency to generate
crises can never be fully grasped and, also, an insight that no one has access
to without some exposure to Marx’s thought.
Science fiction becomes
documentary
In the classic 1955 film Invasion
of the Body Snatchers, the alien force does not attack us head on, unlike
in, say, HG Wells’s The
War of the Worlds. Instead, people are taken over from within, until
nothing is left of their human spirit and emotions. Their bodies are shells
that used to contain a free will and which now labour, go through the motions
of everyday “life”, and function as human simulacra “liberated” from the
unquantifiable essence of human nature. This is something like what would have
transpired if human labour had become perfectly reducible to human capital and
thus fit for insertion into the vulgar economists’ models.
Every non-Marxist economic theory
that treats human and non-human productive inputs as interchangeable assumes
that the dehumanisation of human labour is complete. But if it could ever be
completed, the result would be the end of capitalism as a system capable of
creating and distributing value. For a start, a society of dehumanised automata
would resemble a mechanical watch full of cogs and springs, each with its own
unique function, together producing a “good”: timekeeping. Yet if that society
contained nothing but other automata, timekeeping would not be a “good”. It
would certainly be an “output” but why a “good”? Without real humans to
experience the clock’s function, there can be no such thing as “good” or “bad”.
If capital ever succeeds in
quantifying, and subsequently fully commodifying, labour, as it is constantly
trying to, it will also squeeze that indeterminate, recalcitrant human freedom
from within labour that allows for the generation of value. Marx’s brilliant
insight into the essence of capitalist crises was precisely this: the greater
capitalism’s success in turning labour into a commodity the less the value of
each unit of output it generates, the lower the profit rate and, ultimately,
the nearer the next recession of the economy as a system. The portrayal of
human freedom as an economic category is unique in Marx, making possible a
distinctively dramatic and analytically astute interpretation of capitalism’s
propensity to snatch recession, even depression, from the jaws of growth.
When Marx was writing that labour
is the living, form-giving fire; the transitoriness of things; their
temporality; he was making the greatest contribution any economist has ever
made to our understanding of the acute contradiction buried inside capitalism’s
DNA. When he portrayed capital as a “… force we must submit to … it develops a
cosmopolitan, universal energy which breaks through every limit and every bond
and posts itself as the only policy, the only universality the only limit and
the only bond”, he was highlighting the reality that labour can be purchased by
liquid capital (ie money), in its commodity form, but that it will always carry
with it a will hostile to the capitalist buyer. But Marx was not just making a
psychological, philosophical or political statement. He was, rather, supplying
a remarkable analysis of why the moment that labour (as an unquantifiable
activity) sheds this hostility, it becomes sterile, incapable of producing
value.
At a time when neoliberals have
ensnared the majority in their theoretical tentacles, incessantly regurgitating
the ideology of enhancing labour productivity in an effort to enhance
competitiveness with a view to creating growth etc, Marx’s analysis offers a
powerful antidote. Capital can never win in its struggle to turn labour into an
infinitely elastic, mechanised input, without destroying itself. That is what
neither the neoliberals nor the Keynesians will ever grasp. “If the whole class
of the wage-labourer were to be annihilated by machinery”, wrote Marx “how
terrible that would be for capital, which, without wage-labour, ceases to be
capital!”
What has Marx done for us?
Almost all schools of thought,
including those of some progressive economists, like to pretend that, though
Marx was a powerful figure, very little of his contribution remains relevant
today. I beg to differ. Besides having captured the basic drama of capitalist
dynamics, Marx has given me the tools with which to become immune to the toxic
propaganda of neoliberalism. For example, the idea that wealth is privately
produced and then appropriated by a quasi-illegitimate state, through taxation,
is easy to succumb to if one has not been exposed first to Marx’s poignant
argument that precisely the opposite applies: wealth is collectively produced
and then privately appropriated through social relations of production and
property rights that rely, for their reproduction, almost exclusively on false
consciousness.
In his recent book Never
Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste, the historian of economic thought, Philip
Mirowski, has highlighted the neoliberals’ success in convincing a large array
of people that markets are not just a useful means to an end but also an end in
themselves. According to this view, while collective action and public
institutions are never able to “get it right”, the unfettered operations of
decentralised private interest are guaranteed to produce not only the right
outcomes but also the right desires, character, ethos even. The best example of
this form of neoliberal crassness is, of course, the debate on how to deal with
climate change. Neoliberals have rushed in to argue that, if anything is to be
done, it must take the form of creating a quasi-market for “bads” (eg an
emissions trading scheme), since only markets “know” how to price goods and
bads appropriately. To understand why such a quasi-market solution is bound to
fail and, more importantly, where the motivation comes from for such
“solutions”, one can do much worse than to become acquainted with the logic of
capital accumulation that Marx outlined and the Polish
economist Michal Kalecki adapted to a world ruled by networked oligopolies.
In the 20th century, the two
political movements that sought their roots in Marx’s thought were the
communist and social democratic parties. Both of them, in addition to their
other errors (and, indeed, crimes) failed, to their detriment, to follow Marx’s
lead in a crucial regard: instead of embracing liberty and rationality as their
rallying cries and organising concepts, they opted for equality and justice,
bequeathing the concept of freedom to the neoliberals. Marx was adamant: The
problem with capitalism is not that it is unfair but that it is irrational, as
it habitually condemns whole generations to deprivation and unemployment and
even turns capitalists into angst-ridden automata, living in permanent fear
that unless they commodify their fellow humans fully so as to serve capital
accumulation more efficiently, they will cease to be capitalists. So, if
capitalism appears unjust this is because it enslaves everyone; it wastes human
and natural resources; the same production line that pumps out remarkable
gizmos and untold wealth, also produces deep unhappiness and crises.
Having failed to couch a critique
of capitalism in terms of freedom and rationality, as Marx thought essential,
social democracy and the left in general allowed the neoliberals to usurp the
mantle of freedom and to win a spectacular triumph in the contest of
ideologies.
Perhaps the most significant
dimension of the neoliberal triumph is what has come to be known as the “democratic
deficit”. Rivers of crocodile tears have flowed over the decline of our great
democracies during the past three decades of financialisation and
globalisation. Marx would have laughed long and hard at those who seem
surprised, or upset, by the “democratic deficit”. What was the great objective
behind 19th-century liberalism? It was, as Marx never tired of pointing out, to
separate the economic sphere from the political sphere and to confine politics
to the latter while leaving the economic sphere to capital. It is liberalism’s
splendid success in achieving this long-held goal that we are now observing.
Take a look at South Africa today, more than two decades after Nelson Mandela
was freed and the political sphere, at long last, embraced the whole population.
The ANC’s predicament was that, in order to be allowed to dominate the
political sphere, it had to give up power over the economic one. And if you
think otherwise, I suggest that you talk to the dozens of miners gunned down by
armed guards paid by their employers after they dared demand a wage rise.
Why erratic?
Having explained why I owe whatever understanding of our social world I may possess largely to Karl Marx, I now want to explain why I remain terribly angry with him. In other words, I shall outline why I am by choice an erratic, inconsistent Marxist. Marx committed two spectacular mistakes, one of them an error of omission, the other one of commission. Even today, these mistakes still hamper the left’s effectiveness, especially in Europe.
Marx’s first error – the error of
omission was that he failed to give sufficient thought to the impact of his own
theorising on the world that he was theorising about. His theory is
discursively exceptionally powerful, and Marx had a sense of its power. So how
come he showed no concern that his disciples, people with a better grasp of
these powerful ideas than the average worker, might use the power bestowed upon
them, via Marx’s own ideas, in order to abuse other comrades, to build their
own power base, to gain positions of influence?
Marx’s second error, the one I
ascribe to commission, was worse. It was his assumption that truth about
capitalism could be discovered in the mathematics of his models. This was the
worst disservice he could have delivered to his own theoretical system. The man
who equipped us with human freedom as a first-order economic concept; the
scholar who elevated radical indeterminacy to its rightful place within
political economics; he was the same person who ended up toying around with
simplistic algebraic models, in which labour units were, naturally, fully
quantified, hoping against hope to evince from these equations some additional
insights about capitalism. After his death, Marxist economists wasted long
careers indulging a similar type of scholastic mechanism. Fully immersed in
irrelevant debates on “the transformation problem” and what to do about it,
they eventually became an almost extinct species, as the neoliberal juggernaut
crushed all dissent in its path.
How could Marx be so deluded? Why
did he not recognise that no truth about capitalism can ever spring out of any
mathematical model, however brilliant the modeller may be? Did he not have the
intellectual tools to realise that capitalist dynamics spring from the
unquantifiable part of human labour; ie from a variable that can never be
well-defined mathematically? Of course he did, since he forged these tools! No,
the reason for his error is a little more sinister: just like the vulgar
economists that he so brilliantly admonished (and who continue to dominate the
departments of economics today), he coveted the power that mathematical “proof”
afforded him. Why did Marx not recognise that
no truth about capitalism can ever spring out of any mathematical model?
If I am right, Marx knew what he
was doing. He understood, or had the capacity to know, that a comprehensive
theory of value cannot be accommodated within a mathematical model of a dynamic
capitalist economy. He was, I have no doubt, aware that a proper economic
theory must respect the idea that the rules of the undetermined are themselves
undetermined. In economic terms this meant a recognition that the market power,
and thus the profitability, of capitalists was not necessarily reducible to
their capacity to extract labour from employees; that some capitalists can
extract more from a given pool of labour or from a given community of consumers
for reasons that are external to Marx’s own theory.
Alas, that recognition would be
tantamount to accepting that his “laws” were not immutable. He would have to
concede to competing voices in the trades union movement that his theory was
indeterminate and, therefore, that his pronouncements could not be uniquely and
unambiguously correct. That they were permanently provisional. This determination
to have the complete, closed story, or model, the final word, is something I
cannot forgive Marx for. It proved, after all, responsible for a great deal of
error and, more significantly, authoritarianism. Errors and authoritarianism
that are largely responsible for the left’s current impotence as a force of
good and as a check on the abuses of reason and liberty that the neoliberal
crew are overseeing today.
Mrs Thatcher’s lesson
I moved to England to attend university in September 1978, six months or so before Margaret Thatcher’s victory changed Britain forever. Watching the Labour government disintegrate, under the weight of its degenerate social democratic programme, led me to a serious error: to the thought that Thatcher’s victory could be a good thing, delivering to Britain’s working and middle classes the short, sharp shock necessary to reinvigorate progressive politics; to give the left a chance to create a fresh, radical agenda for a new type of effective, progressive politics.
Even as unemployment doubled and
then trebled, under Thatcher’s radical neoliberal interventions, I continued to
harbour hope that Lenin was right: “Things have to get worse before they get
better.” As life became nastier, more brutish and, for many, shorter, it occurred
to me that I was tragically in error: things could get worse in perpetuity,
without ever getting better. The hope that the deterioration of public goods,
the diminution of the lives of the majority, the spread of deprivation to every
corner of the land would, automatically, lead to a renaissance of the left was
just that: hope. The reality was, however,
painfully different. With every turn of the recession’s screw, the left became
more introverted, less capable of producing a convincing progressive agenda
and, meanwhile, the working class was being divided between those who dropped
out of society and those co-opted into the neoliberal mindset. My hope that
Thatcher would inadvertently bring about a new political revolution was well
and truly bogus. All that sprang out of Thatcherism were extreme
financialisation, the triumph of the shopping mall over the corner store, the
fetishisation of housing and Tony Blair.
Instead of radicalising British
society, the recession that Thatcher’s government so carefully engineered, as
part of its class war against organised labour and against the public
institutions of social security and redistribution that had been established
after the war, permanently destroyed the very possibility of radical,
progressive politics in Britain. Indeed, it rendered impossible the very notion
of values that transcended what the market determined as the “right” price. The lesson Thatcher taught me
about the capacity of a long‑lasting recession to undermine progressive
politics, is one that I carry with me into today’s European crisis. It is,
indeed, the most important determinant of my stance in relation to the crisis.
It is the reason I am happy to confess to the sin I am accused of by some of my
critics on the left: the sin of choosing not to propose radical political
programs that seek to exploit the crisis as an opportunity to overthrow
European capitalism, to dismantle the awful eurozone, and to undermine the
European Union of the cartels and the bankrupt bankers.
Yes, I would love to put forward
such a radical agenda. But, no, I am not prepared to commit the same error
twice. What good did we achieve in Britain in the early 1980s by promoting an
agenda of socialist change that British society scorned while falling headlong
into Thatcher’s neoliberal trap? Precisely none. What good will it do today to
call for a dismantling of the eurozone, of the European Union itself, when
European capitalism is doing its utmost to undermine the eurozone, the European
Union, indeed itself? A Greek or a Portuguese or an
Italian exit from the eurozone would soon lead to a fragmentation of European
capitalism, yielding a seriously recessionary surplus region east of the Rhine
and north of the Alps, while the rest of Europe is would be in the grip of
vicious stagflation. Who do you think would benefit from this development? A
progressive left, that will rise Phoenix-like from the ashes of Europe’s public
institutions? Or the Golden Dawn Nazis, the assorted neofascists, the
xenophobes and the spivs? I have absolutely no doubt as to which of the two
will do best from a disintegration of the eurozone. I, for one, am not prepared to
blow fresh wind into the sails of this postmodern version of the 1930s. If this
means that it is we, the suitably erratic Marxists, who must try to save
European capitalism from itself, so be it. Not out of love for European
capitalism, for the eurozone, for Brussels, or for the European Central Bank,
but just because we want to minimise the unnecessary human toll from this
crisis.
What should Marxists do?
Europe’s elites are behaving
today as if they understand neither the nature of the crisis that they are
presiding over, nor its implications for the future of European civilisation.
Atavistically, they are choosing to plunder the diminishing stocks of the weak
and the dispossessed in order to plug the gaping holes of the financial sector,
refusing to come to terms with the unsustainability of the task.
Yet with Europe’s elites deep in
denial and disarray, the left must admit that we are just not ready to plug the
chasm that a collapse of European capitalism would open up with a functioning
socialist system. Our task should then be twofold. First, to put forward an
analysis of the current state of play that non-Marxist, well-meaning Europeans
who have been lured by the sirens of neoliberalism, find insightful. Second, to
follow this sound analysis up with proposals for stabilising Europe – for
ending the downward spiral that, in the end, reinforces only the bigots.
Let me now conclude with two confessions. First, while I am happy to defend as genuinely radical the pursuit of a modest agenda for stabilising a system that I criticise, I shall not pretend to be enthusiastic about it. This may be what we must do, under the present circumstances, but I am sad that I shall probably not be around to see a more radical agenda being adopted. Europe’s elites are behaving as if they understand neither the nature of the crisis, nor its implications for the future
My final confession is of a
highly personal nature: I know that I run the risk of, surreptitiously,
lessening the sadness from ditching any hope of replacing capitalism in my
lifetime by indulging a feeling of having become agreeable to the circles of
polite society. The sense of self-satisfaction from being feted by the high and
mighty did begin, on occasion, to creep up on me. And what a non-radical, ugly,
corruptive and corrosive sense it was.
My personal nadir came at an
airport. Some moneyed outfit had invited me to give a keynote speech on the
European crisis and had forked out the ludicrous sum necessary to buy me a
first-class ticket. On my way back home, tired and with several flights under
my belt, I was making my way past the long queue of economy passengers, to get
to my gate. Suddenly I noticed, with horror, how easy it was for my mind to be
infected with the sense that I was entitled to bypass the hoi polloi. I
realised how readily I could forget that which my leftwing mind had always
known: that nothing succeeds in reproducing itself better than a false sense of
entitlement. Forging alliances with reactionary forces, as I think we should do
to stabilise Europe today, brings us up against the risk of becoming co-opted,
of shedding our radicalism through the warm glow of having “arrived” in the
corridors of power.
Radical confessions, like the one I have attempted here, are perhaps the only programmatic antidote to ideological slippage that threatens to turn us into cogs of the machine. If we are to forge alliances with our political adversaries we must avoid becoming like the socialists who failed to change the world but succeeded in improving their private circumstances. The trick is to avoid the revolutionary maximalism that, in the end, helps the neoliberals bypass all opposition to their self-defeating policies and to retain in our sights capitalism’s inherent failures while trying to save it, for strategic purposes, from itself.
(This article is adapted from
a lecture originally delivered at the 6th Subversive Festival in Zagreb in 2013).
No comments:
Post a Comment